What's new

European ‘Project’ Not Irreversible, New Paper Says

Yeah, no not really.



USSR GDP – History of Russia

GDP%20Graph_US_USSR_b.jpg


GDP%20Rate_b.jpg


http://phobos.ramapo.edu/~theed/Cold_War/f_Conclusion/media/

its gdp per capita not gdp

List of countries by GDP (PPP) per capita - Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia


great what has changed today? America has still the highest gdp per capita even in comparison to UK?
Gdpercapita.PNG


If Britain were a U.S. state, it would be the second-poorest, behind Alabama and before Mississippi - The Washington Post

so whats your point? If you suck hide between your bigger brother is that your point?

For people who live in these towns it is. The coal mining town my parents grew up in had a strong sense of community and family values. Then it became a heroin drenched wasteland. Virtually every country in Europe except Germany has a crisis in terms of manufacturing industry which is where the current crisis originates from.
Yeah but what manufactering does germany? Its high valued machinery? Do you want to work for 1 dollar to make mcdonalds toys? Is this the jobs you want back?
 
. . .
seriously someone should ban you racist


:bunny: This is not Soviet Russia were discontent with the party line is forbidden.Suck it up comrade Trollintski

If you dislike me so much you could start by NOT tagging me every time in your retarded,ruble paid threads.
 
.
its gdp per capita not gdp

Senheiser, I have ALSO included a source about GDP.

For the second time already:

Throughout its history, USSR GDP (Gross Domestic Product) has been considerably lower compared to US GDP. At its highest, Soviet GDP reached around 60% of US GDP, but by 1989 it had shrunk to around half the size of US GDP.
By 1989, just before the Soviet Union’s collapse, USSR GDP was reported to be $2,500 billion, compared to US GDP of $4,862 billion. In terms of per capita GDP or per capita income, this translates into $8,700 per capita in the USSR, and $19,800 in the USA.

USSR GDP – History of Russia

But herer's another source if you prefer: http://kushnirs.org/macroeconomics/gdp/gdp_ussr.html

As we can see form this source:

In 1970, Soviet GDP (433.4 billion USD) was 40.28% of the American GDP (1075.9 billion USD).

In 1980, Soviet GDP (940 billion USD) was 32.83% of the American GDP (2862.5 billion USD).

In 1990, Soviet GDP (776.8 billion USD) was 12.99% of the American GDP (5979.6 billion USD).
 
.
:bunny: This is not Soviet Russia were discontent with the party line is forbidden.Suck it up comrade Trollintski
This same poster was saying a few days ago that the 300 who died on MH17 had it coming. It seems he likes to dish it out but can't take it.
 
.
It's the complete opposite. Cheap products from factories in the east put industries in the West out of business. This is true everywhere except Germany who make sure the EU economy runs in their interests.
Most of the industrial giants of Eastern Europe, like the Gdansk shipyards, or the Hungarian plant "Ikarus" (was at one time the largest manufacturer of buses in Europe) are now closed, or working at 5-10% of their previous power. The scheme is simple - western "investor" buys plant, promises mountains of gold, and then just closes it. As a result, to the streets of London comes another 100,000 of Poles and Balts, willing to work under the same conditions as Negros, Arabs or Asians. If you had said something like that to Pole or Balt in 1970 - he would hit you, because back in those days they had pride and dignity.
 
.
Most of the industrial giants of Eastern Europe, like the Gdansk shipyards, or the Hungarian plant "Ikarus" (was at one time the largest manufacturer of buses in Europe) are now closed, or working at 5-10% of their previous power. The scheme is simple - western "investor" buys plant, promises mountains of gold, and then just closes it. As a result, to the streets of London comes another 100,000 of Poles and Balts, willing to work under the same conditions as Negros, Arabs or Asians. If you had said something like that to Pole or Balt in 1970 - he would hit you, because back in those days they had pride and dignity.
You're talking to the wrong country here. It's Germany and France who buy up factories in Eastern Europe. British industry and agriculture has been destroyed by the EU just as much as in Poland and Hungary.
 
.
You're talking to the wrong country here. It's Germany and France who buy up factories in Eastern Europe. Britain has very little economic interests there.
I'm not saying that only UK did that. The fact that the industry in Eastern Europe for some mysterious reason, did not rise to the level of Western Europe. Moreover, the industrial areas of Eastern Europe turn into scenery for films about the apocalypse. And poor workers are forced to seek for the worst jobs in the West.
 
.
http://ftalphaville.ft.com/2014/10/20/2012922/germanreluctance/

Spending versus consolidation, German political capital edition
Cardiff Garcia Author alerts | Oct 20 08:30

Two sets of charts from BCA Research with unclear implications:




One interpretation of these charts is that they explain the ostensibly casual reluctance of German policymakers to embrace aggressive demand-stimulating policies for Europe — whether that means dropping their opposition to Mario Draghi’s pursuit of a sufficiently big QE program, or lowering their resistance to more budget flexibility for the French and Italian governments.

If the German public, whatever the latest dour indicators, feels good both about the domestic economy and about the country’s influence on Europe, what motivation is there for German policymakers to risk their reputations as thrifty guardians of public finances and purchasing power?

But the researchers at BCA have a different, more hopeful interpretation. A consensus is forming throughout Europe, they write, in which structural reforms are accepted as a required tradeoff for policies that spur growth:

Will the German public and policymakers accept the quid pro quo of reforms for spending?

German politicians will publically maintain their hardline rhetoric on fiscal consolidation, but the German public clearly believes that things are going well at home (Chart 5) and Berlin is in the driver’s seat when it comes to pursuing German interests at the EU level (Chart 9). In other words, Berlin has plenty of spare political capital that will allow it to give ground to the rest of Europe, especially as Merkel’s CDU shares the governing coalition with the center-left Social Democratic Party and not with the mildly euroskeptic FDP anymore.

Finally, it is important to understand that Germany is not in charge of Europe. Many of our clients and colleagues often speak of German power as if the Wehrmacht has returned to the streets of Paris and Rome. The reality is that Germany is only 27% of euro area GDP and it depends on the periphery plus France for 18% of its exports, or 8% of GDP. It would ultimately be suicidal for Germany to allow the periphery to descend into a full out deflationary spiral due to austerity.

A consensus belief in reforms-for-stimulus is what Mario Draghi advocated in his remarkable speech at Jackson Hole. Meanwhile the German disinclination to support stimulative policies increasingly runs against the prevailing sentiment, whose voices have spiked in number and volume.

Are the strategists right to believe that German policymakers are likely to yield, eventually? We don’t know and remain sceptical, especially given the unreadableidiosyncrasies of German politics, but here’s hoping.
 
.
Europe’s Brush with Debt by Hans-Werner Sinn - Project Syndicate


POLITICS
11a3ccb7dc2b0d8e159396b36738cfec.square.png

HANS-WERNER SINN
Hans-Werner Sinn, Professor of Economics and Public Finance at the University of Munich, is President of the Ifo Institute for Economic Research and serves on the German economy ministry’s Advisory Council. He is the author, most recently, of The Euro Trap: On Bursting Bubbles, Budgets, and Beliefs, Oxford University Press, 2014.

OCT 22, 2014
Europe’s Brush with Debt
MUNICH – French Prime Minister Manuel Valls and his Italian counterpart, Matteo Renzi, have declared – or at least insinuated – that they will not comply with the fiscal compact to which all of the eurozone’s member countries agreed in 2012; instead, they intend to run up fresh debts. Their stance highlights a fundamental flaw in the structure of the European Monetary Union – one that Europe’s leaders must recognize and address before it is too late.

The fiscal compact – formally the Treaty on Stability, Coordination, and Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union – was the quid pro quo for Germany to approve the European Stability Mechanism (ESM), which was essentially a collective bailout package. The compact sets a strict ceiling for a country’s structural budget deficit and stipulates that public-debt ratios in excess of 60% of GDP must be reduced yearly by one-twentieth of the difference between the current ratio and the target.

Yet France’s debt/GDP ratio will rise to 96% by the end of this year, from 91% in 2012, while Italy’s will reach 135%, up from 127% in 2012. The effective renunciation of the fiscal compact by Valls and Renzi suggests that these ratios will rise even further in the coming years.

In this context, eurozone leaders must ask themselves tough questions about the sustainability of the current system for managing debt in the EMU. They should begin by considering the two possible models for ensuring stability and debt sustainability in a monetary union: the mutualization model and the liability model.

Europe has so far stuck to the mutualization model, in which individual states’ debts are underwritten by a common central bank or fiscal bailout system, ensuring security for investors and largely eliminating interest-rate spreads among countries, regardless of their level of indebtedness. In order to prevent the artificial reduction of interest rates from encouraging countries to borrow excessively, political debt brakes are instituted.

In the eurozone, mutualization was realized through generous ESM bailouts and some €1 trillion ($1.27 trillion) worth of TARGET2 credit from national printing presses for the crisis-stricken countries. Moreover, the European Central Bank pledged to protect these countries from default free of charge through its “outright monetary transactions” (OMT) scheme – that is, by promising to purchase their sovereign debt on secondary markets – which functions roughly as Eurobonds would. The supposed hardening of the debt ceiling in 2012 adhered to this model.

The alternative – the liability model – requires that each state take responsibility for its own debts, with its creditors bearing the costs of a default. Faced with that risk, creditors demand higher interest rates from the outset or refuse to grant additional credit, thereby imposing a measure of discipline on debtors.

The best example of the liability model is the United States. When US states like California, Illinois, or Minnesota get into fiscal trouble, no one expects the other states or the federal government to bail them out, let alone that the Federal Reserve will guarantee or purchase their bonds.

Indeed, the Fed, unlike the ECB, does not buy any bonds from individual states; investors must bear the costs of any state insolvency. In 1975, New York had to pledge its future tax revenues to its creditors in order to remain solvent.

Of course, the US was not always so strict. Shortly after its founding, it tried debt mutualization, with Alexander Hamilton, America’s first Treasury secretary, describing the scheme in 1791 as the “cement” for a new American federation.

But, as it turned out, the mutualization model – used again in 1813 during the second war against the British – fueled a credit bubble, which collapsed in 1837 and thrust nine of the 29 US states and territories into bankruptcy. The unresolved debt problem exacerbated tensions over the slavery issue, which triggered the Civil War in 1861.

In this sense, as the historian Harold James has noted, mutualization turned out to be dynamite, not cement, for the new US federation. Only after the Civil War did the US decide to operate the federation according to the liability model – an approach that has underpinned stability and limited individual states’ debt levels ever since.

For Europe’s leaders, the withdrawal by France and Italy from the fiscal compact should serve as a clear sign that the mutualization model is not working for the eurozone, either. Following the Fed’s example, the ECB should abolish its OMT program – which, according to Germany’s Constitutional Court, does not comply with EU treaty law anyway.

Furthermore, the ECB should reintroduce the requirement that TARGET2 debts be repaid with gold, as occurred in the US before 1975 to settle balances among the districts of the Federal Reserve System. Perhaps even the fiscal compact itself should be reconsidered.

Such measures would serve notice to investors that they cannot hope to be saved by the printing press in times of crisis, and would thus compel them to demand higher interest rates or deter them from granting credit in the first place. This would lead to greater discipline among the eurozone’s indebted countries and save Europe from a debt avalanche that could ultimately drive currently solvent states into bankruptcy and destroy the European integration project.

Europe’s Brush with Debt by Hans-Werner Sinn - Project Syndicate


Read more at Europe’s Brush with Debt by Hans-Werner Sinn - Project Syndicate
 
.
Stress Tests in Europe: Interview with Mohamed El-Erian - SPIEGEL ONLINE

EU Banking Stress Tests: 'Far-Reaching Reforms Are Needed'
Interview Conducted by Martin Hesse


Getty Images
Gathering clouds over Frankfurt can be seen from the new ECB headquarters, still under construction.

On Sunday, Europe will release the results of its banking stress tests. In an interview, former PIMCO head Mohamed El-Erian speaks with SPIEGEL about what to expect and how Europe's core countries are failing to adequately confront a flagging economy.

SPIEGEL: Mr. El-Erian, the results of the stress test on European banks will be published on Sunday. If you had a billion dollars to bet for or against European banks, what would you do?



El-Erian: Stock markets are altogether overvalued; people took risks in financial markets that were too high. Banking stocks often exaggerate the development: If stock markets rise, bank shares rise higher. If stock markets fall, they fall deeper. Therefore, I would buy neither stocks nor bank bonds prior to a correction. I would focus on highly secured banking bonds.
SPIEGEL: How poorly are Europe's banks doing?



About Mohamed El-Erian
  • image-329977-panoV9free-gugp.jpg

    REUTERS
    Mohamed El-Erian, 56, was the CEO of the global investment firm PIMCO until March of this year. Currently, he is the chief economic advisor to Allianz, which owns PIMCO.
El-Erian: Soon, banks will no longer be the biggest risk to the financial system and the economy. And five years from now, many credit institutions will be smaller than they are today, having discontinued some types of business, and will better support the real economy.
SPIEGEL: Why only then? What has to happen first?

El-Erian: Not all banks will pass the ECB comprehensive assessment with flying colors. Some need capital, others need to downsize. Many banks haven't yet solved their culture problems and legal disputes. Foul credits and securities need to be further reduced. This is even more of a problem as the economic environment is now getting worse again.

SPIEGEL: In Germany there is an expectation that banks from the periphery of the European Union will prove weaker than financial institutions in core EU countries. Do you share that view?

El-Erian: That is putting it too simply. Peripheral countries like Ireland and Greece are at different stages of mastering the crisis. There will be banks in core countries of the euro zone that won't look very good in the test and others that will pass with ease. But this is exactly the problem: So far investors have been badly informed and couldn't distinguish between healthy and less healthy banks -- and therefore had less trust in all of them.

SPIEGEL: Will this examination of their balance sheets change that?

El-Erian: The exercise will provide a good momentary assessment of the system's condition. I'm convinced that the test is serious and strict. Furthermore, the comprehensive, and henceforth better comparable, balance sheet data will allow investors and analysts to run their own tests, with their own assumptions, if they consider these more realistic than the ECB scenarios. That is why this test will drive away thecloud of uncertainty which is hovering over the European economy.

SPIEGEL: Was Europe's reaction to the financial crisis wrong?

El-Erian: Of course the euro zone could have done better. The high unemployment rate, particularly among the youth, is alarming. But the same applies for the US, UK or Japan -- there is too little investment overall, and reforms to labor and production markets are incomplete. With the exception of Germany, the highly developed economies slept through their opportunity to renew themselves.

SPIEGEL: Why is that?

El-Erian: The US, the UK, Ireland, Iceland, Greece and other countries fell in love with the wrong growth model. They believed that -- following the agrarian economy, industrialization and the service economy -- the primacy of financial industries represented the next step of capitalism. Financial service providers that supported the rest of the economy turned into banks serving only their own interests.

SPIEGEL: What has changed in that regard? Central banks in Europe are still mainly focused on supporting the banks.

El-Erian: No. Neither the Fed nor the ECB believe anymore that this model is sustainable on the long term. With their loose fiscal policy, they merely want to build a bridge until a system has been established in which banks play a serving role again.

SPIEGEL: They've been building this bridge for quite some time.

El-Erian: Correct. And I'm afraid that the malaise and the weak growth will be here for a long time. Some politicians still don't realize how serious the situation is. They believe it's only a cyclical problem, just as there have always been periods of economic downturn and periods of boom. But the long-term tendency points downwards; the capacity to grow is declining continuously.

SPIEGEL: The ECB has now begun buying securities from banks on a large scale. Will that help the economy?



El-Erian: The far-reaching reforms that are needed can only come from governments. They have every opportunity to avoid a new downward spiral. That's why this is so frustrating. It's merely a question of political will and lasting implementation.
SPIEGEL: Should Germany take on more leadership responsibility?

El-Erian: The three biggest economies of the euro zone -- Germany, France and Italy -- are facing headwinds. But instead of pulling together, the three insist on opposing positions. In the end, all sides will have to move. Structural reforms are required in almost all European countries. But it is good that Germany has now started to talk more about investments, such as into infrastructure, for example.
 
.
Europe’s Fiscal Wormhole by Guntram B. Wolff - Project Syndicate


BUSINESS & FINANCE
56cc7af0ec08685903db66f2162644a7.square.png

GUNTRAM B. WOLFF
Guntram B. Wolff is Director of Bruegel, the Brussels-based economic think tank.

OCT 23, 2014
Europe’s Fiscal Wormhole
BRUSSELS – The International Monetary Fund now estimates a 30% risk of deflation in the eurozone, and growth figures within the monetary union continue to disappoint. But policymakers seem trapped in a cat’s cradle of economic, political, and legal constraints that is preventing effective action. The fulfillment of policy rules appears to be impossible without growth, but growth appears to be impossible without breaking the rules.

German Finance Minister Wolfgang Schäuble is politically committed to outdoing his country’s tough domestic fiscal framework to secure what he calls a “black zero” budget. The French government is working to regain credibility on reform promises made in exchange for delays on fiscal adjustment, and Italy, with one of the highest debt burdens in the eurozone, has little room to use fiscal policy. Meanwhile, the European Central Bank is constrained by doubts about the legality of its “outright monetary transactions” (OMT) scheme – sovereign-bond purchases that could result in a redistributive fiscal policy.

With all of the rules pointing toward recession, how can Europe boost recovery?

A two-year €400 billion ($510 billion) public-investment program, financed with European Investment Bank bonds, would be the best way to overcome Europe’s current impasse. Borrowing by the EIB has no implications in terms of European fiscal rules. It is recorded neither as new debt nor as a deficit for any of the member states, which means that new government spending could be funded without affecting national fiscal performance.

Thus, some of the investment spending currently planned at the national level could be financed via European borrowing to relieve national budgets. Such an indirect way of dealing with strict rules would also be easier than starting long and wearying negotiations on changes to the fiscal framework.

The EIB is worried that such a scheme could come at the cost of its triple-A rating. Indeed, though it can currently borrow at 1.6% on a long maturity, it has used its recent capital-raising exercise to reduce leverage rather than substantially increase its loan portfolio, as would be warranted at a time of retrenchment in private lending. In any case, a rating change would hardly affect funding costs in the current low-yield environment, as lower-rated sovereigns have demonstrated.

In addition, the ECB could purchase EIB bonds on secondary markets, which would help to keep funding costs low – or even reduce them. More important, purchases of EIB bonds would enable the ECB to undertake quantitative easing without triggering the degree of controversy implied by intervening in 18 separate sovereign-bond markets, where concerns that ECB purchases would affect the relative pricing of sovereigns are very real.

Already, €200 billion of EIB bonds are available. Adding €400 billion would increase the pool substantially. Together with asset-backed securities, covered bonds, and corporate bonds, €1 trillion of assets – the threshold widely thought to make quantitative easing by the ECB credible – would be available for purchase.

A central question, of course, concerns the type of government spending that should qualify as investment spending, and which European investment projects should be supported. It will be impossible to define new and sensible European projects worth €200 billion per year. Common projects such as the European energy union will need more time to be precisely defined. As a result, the bulk of investment now will have to come from national policymakers.

In part, this means that existing infrastructure projects that are supposed to be financed from national budgets could be funded by the EIB. By removing some of the burden from national budgets, the current decline in public investment could be reversed.

Some of the new resources could also be used to allow for budget consolidation in France without pro-cyclical cuts. France could get this helping hand in complying with the fiscal rules in exchange for serious and necessary structural reforms, as could Italy, where EIB-funded bonds would provide a much-needed growth stimulus without new government commitments. In Germany, the freed-up resources could be used to accelerate existing investment projects while still meeting its black-zero pledge.

Similar arrangements could be found for the other eurozone countries. To prevent the misuse of money, the European Commission should vet all national investment projects. More broadly, the program would be an important step toward establishing the eurozone’s missing fiscal union. That goal will be reached more quickly once the benefits of achieving it are apparent to all.

Europe’s Fiscal Wormhole by Guntram B. Wolff - Project Syndicate


Read more at Europe’s Fiscal Wormhole by Guntram B. Wolff - Project Syndicate
 
.
Optimizing the Eurozone by Koichi Hamada - Project Syndicate


BUSINESS & FINANCE
18ac81ec15f4cde45bc513cffa291dcc.square.png

KOICHI HAMADA
Koichi Hamada, Special Economic Adviser to Japanese Prime Minister Shinzo Abe, is Professor of Economics at Yale University and Professor Emeritus of Economics at the University of Tokyo.

OCT 28, 2014
Optimizing the Eurozone
TOKYO – The eurozone is facing a bleak economic outlook, with growth remaining stagnant and the threat of deflation looming large. The economist Martin Feldstein, who was skeptical of the initiative from the start, now calls it a “failure.” Is Feldstein right, or could the eurozone become the “optimal currency area” that its creators believed it to be?

Answering this question requires, first and foremost, an understanding of the costs and benefits of various exchange-rate systems. The International Monetary Fund was established 70 years ago to manage an “adjustable peg” system – a hybrid system in which exchange rates were usually fixed to the US dollar, but could be adjusted occasionally to improve the country’s competitive position in export markets.

For the first few decades, this system leaned heavily toward “peg,” owing to the US dollar’s direct convertibility to gold. This brought significant stability to the global monetary order, following the competitive devaluations of the 1930s that some economists considered damaging.

But the fixed exchange-rate system also undermined the United States’ capacity to manage its balance of payments. That is why, in 1971, President Richard Nixon unilaterally abandoned the dollar’s convertibility to gold, leaving major currencies’ exchange rates to float against one another.

Such a system provides important advantages – most notably, it enables the US Federal Reserve to pump money into the economy to prevent or halt a recession. But it also carries serious risks, exemplified in the trade imbalances that emerged in the 1980s.

From 1980 to 1985, the US dollar appreciated by 50% against the currencies of Japan, West Germany, France, and the United Kingdom; America’s current-account deficit was approaching 3% of GDP; and its top four competitors had massive surpluses and negative GDP growth. In order to correct these imbalances, the five countries signed the Plaza Accord, in which they agreed to intervene in currency markets to devalue the dollar.

It is against this background that the euro was born, with the goal of boosting European economies by expanding their “local” market, lowering transaction costs, and facilitating the flow of information. In 1991, the loss of monetary-policy independence seemed like a worthwhile trade-off for Europe’s economies; today, it seems that it may have been a mistake.

In fact, America’s experience in the 1960s should have warned the eurozone’s creators that tying national monetary authorities’ hands might not be such a good idea. That would not be the case if the eurozone operated according to Robert Mundell’s vision of an optimal currency area, with labor and capital adjustments replacing exchange-rate adjustment, and shocks being homogeneous (rather than asymmetric). Moreover, Germany’s experience with reunification suggests that political union is integral to such a union’s success.

The eurozone’s performance has not met any of these criteria. Most notably, eurozone countries have faced powerful asymmetric shocks, to which their lack of independent monetary-policy instruments made it virtually impossible to respond. As a result, they have struggled with recurring economic crisis.

To understand the corrective power of monetary policy, one need only consider Japan’s recent progress in escaping from decades of stagflation. Monetary expansion was one of the three key features of Prime Minister Shinzo Abe’s economic strategy – an approach that could have been implemented years ago to halt the yen’s sharp appreciation. The problem was that Bank of Japan Governor Haruhiko Kuroda’s predecessors behaved as if they were bound by a fixed exchange-rate regime.

Unlike in Japan, eurozone countries’ failure to implement bold monetary-policy measures is not a choice. The only available monetary-policy tool is to change collectively the euro’s value relative to outside currencies. But use of this tool is constrained by the wide discrepancies among individual countries’ appetite for inflationary or deflationary price levels.

To be sure, European economic integration – a process that, one might say, culminated with the eurozone’s establishment – also brought clear political benefits. As Robert Schuman promised when he conceived the idea of a European Community, integration has prevented the recurrence of war between Germany and France. But whether monetary union on such a large scale was necessary to achieve this goal is dubious.

In any case, the eurozone exists – and, at this point, it would be exceedingly difficult to dismantle it fully. Given this, the goal today should be to move toward an optimal currency area.

For starters, Europe’s leaders must recognize that the eurozone, as it is currently constituted, is larger than Europe’s optimal currency area. Some of its member countries – certainly Greece, and probably Italy and Spain – need an independent monetary policy. Otherwise, they will continue to go from one crisis to the next, with countries that do fall within the optimal currency area – for example, Germany and France – facing the consequences.

Once membership in the eurozone is optimized, the next step will be to ensure continued progress toward political consolidation. The result will be a stronger, more efficient eurozone – one in which the benefits really do outweigh the costs.

Optimizing the Eurozone by Koichi Hamada - Project Syndicate


Read more at Optimizing the Eurozone by Koichi Hamada - Project Syndicate
 
.
£1.7bn EU Bill Puts UK One Step Closer to 'Brexit' | Chatham House

£1.7bn EU Bill Puts UK One Step Closer to 'Brexit'
29 October 2014

BeggIanCrop.jpg

Professor Iain Begg
Associate Fellow, Europe Programme


Is the call for an additional contribution to the EU budget as outrageous as David Cameron has asserted, or simply the normal application of EU rules and mechanisms? In reality, it is a bit of both, but there is more to the story.
20141029CameronEU.jpg
British Prime Minister David Cameron leaves the European Union summit at EU headquarters in Brussels on 34 October 2014. Photo by Getty Images.
When David Cameron emerged from last Friday’s European Council meeting, the indignation on show could not have been greater: ‘If people think I am paying that bill on 1 December, they have another thing coming.’ He was responding to new figures revealed last week which call for an additional £1.7 billion contribution to the EU budget from the UK. In what is a routine recalculation, several other countries, including the Netherlands, have been asked to pay proportionately more than the UK, while Germany, France and 17 others will pay less.

Is this as outrageous as the prime minister has asserted, or simply the normal application of EU rules and mechanisms? In reality, it is a little bit of both, but there are three elements to the story.

The first is that most of the EU’s revenue derives from an income stream known as the GNI (gross national income) resource. GNI is a close relative of the more familiar term GDP (gross domestic product), differing largely because of how profits from abroad are counted. As such, it reflects relative prosperity and, thus, ability to pay – a widely accepted principle of taxation. The amount called from each member state is a fixed proportion of its GNI, though the true cost to the UK is then attenuated by the famous rebate negotiated in 1984 by Margaret Thatcher. Despite some of the headlines about a ‘tax on prosperity’, the principle that countries pay more when GNI rises has been accepted since the system was introduced over a quarter of a century ago. In some years the UK has benefited, in others it has had to pay, as have all other member states.

Second, the GNI resource was something that British negotiators pushed strongly for when it was first introduced, and that the UK has fought to retain ever since. Others have argued for a tax to be assigned to the EU, in much the same way as council tax in the UK or sales taxes in the United States are deemed to belong to the local tier of government. But the UK, along with other net contributors to the EU budget, notably Germany, has been adamant that there should be no such tax. The total amount called from the GNI resource is determined by the spending from the EU budget and, in this regard, acts as a residual resource to ensure that the EU budget always balances (as it is required to do by treaty). Spending is not entirely predictable because the rigorous controls which countries like the UK insist that the EU impose have meant that some projects only become eligible to receive funding much later than anticipated.

The third consideration is that this year’s calculations are unusual, because the statisticians who construct the GNI data recently completed a methodological review of how national accounts are compiled. These are once-in-a-decade exercises, intended to reflect new insights into how income is generated and advances in data collection. The results revealed that the UK, and a number of the others now being asked to pay more, have been underestimating their prosperity. Normally this would not be that significant, but one of the new factors taken into account is the scope of the hidden economy. In particular, new estimates have been made of the extent of the drug and prostitution markets, something that Germany was apparently already doing.

These data corrections are well-known to the UK authorities and the spicier bits of the new methodology made the news headlines over the summer. Nor is it a form of correction that the Treasury can plausibly claim not to have expected. Indeed, in the late 1980s, Italy revalued its GDP and GNI substantially after introducing new ways of estimating the size of its hidden economy. Overnight, Italy overtook the UK – known at the time as il sorpasso (the over-taking) – but also reportedly drawing the retort from Thatcher that the Italians could henceforth pay more towards the EU budget. Moreover, it is ingrained into Treasury officials that they should be alert to any statistical manipulation that would increase GNI, precisely because of this sort of effect. Therefore, the prime minister is either being disingenuous in claiming that the effects of the re-basing of GNI were unexpected, or he knew full well and decided, nevertheless, to exploit it for immediate political purposes.

Other countries and the European Commission insist that the rules are clear and that Britain will have to pay, implying little room for manoeuvre for the prime minister. Perhaps some fault will be discovered in the calculations, allowing a more palatable figure to emerge. There is also a possibility that enough pressure will be brought to bear on the net winners to persuade them to postpone or average out the introduction of the new GNI estimates, reducing the amount the new net losers will have to pay this year. However, tax-payers in other countries will wonder why their governments should agree to pay more to help the British prime minister mollify eurosceptics at home. Postponing the bills would also be tricky because the EU is legally banned from borrowing.

Leaving aside whether Cameron’s stance leaves wiggle-room to pay subsequently (though only after the Rochester and Strood by-election), the new dispute is revealing about his approach to the EU. It follows his ill-judged campaign to prevent Jean-Claude Juncker becoming president of the European Commission. Two conclusions can be drawn: first, that not enough effort is made to understand how the EU functions or to form alliances to head off potential trouble; and second, that there is too much of a tendency to shoot from the hip. This is a conjunction that can only add to the prospects of further imbroglios and a growing probability of a Brexit.
 
.

Latest posts

Pakistan Defence Latest Posts

Pakistan Affairs Latest Posts

Back
Top Bottom