LeveragedBuyout
SENIOR MEMBER
- Joined
- May 16, 2014
- Messages
- 1,958
- Reaction score
- 60
- Country
- Location
Excellent article. We finally get some detail about the reform process, and the conflicting drives that are slowing the process down. If Xi succeeds, perhaps he should rename the CCP to the "Chinese Capitalist Party," but if the reactionary wing of the CCP succeeds, then we'll be in for a wild ride over the next few years.
---
Guest post: China’s state enterprise reform could strengthen state
Sep 5, 2014 1:00amby guest writer
00
By Bo Zhuang of Trusted Sources
Overhauling state-owned enterprises (SOEs) is key to the Chinese growth story for the next 10 years. But, while the approach being taken by the Xi Jinping leadership acknowledges the need for change, it also stresses the parallel need to strengthen the Communist Party State. This could mean reform will take a rather different form to the assumptions of markets, which have risen on the back of expectations of market-friendly change.
Some elements of the reforms are starting to take shape. The State Assets Supervisory and Administrative Commission (SASAC), the national SOE umbrella organization, has proposed two new ownership forms. One involves state asset-holding companies to manage state-owned capital on the lines of Singapore’s Temasek. The State Development and Investment Corporation (SDIC) and the China National Cereals, Oils and Foodstuffs Corporation (COFCO) will be the first two platforms for this. Meanwhile, Sinopharm Group and the China National Building Materials Group will participate in a pilot programme aimed at mixed-ownership to give private capital bigger equity stakes in SOEs.
The XinXing Cathay International Group, China Energy Conservation Investment Corporation, Sinopharm and China National Building Materials will be in a scheme to let directors decide the assignment, evaluation and remuneration of senior executives.
The chosen companies are, for the most part, attractive investment targets. But the programme does not address two fundamental issues: breaking up monopolies and equality of political and legal status for private enterprises and SOEs. In addition, two major questions run through what will be a long process – the extent to which the state will relinquish control and the nature of “mixed ownership”.
The result could be what is known as a “mixed ownership monopoly model” with private capital boosting the resources of already-dominant state groups and thus strengthening their positions at the commanding heights of the economy. Genuine reform would involve opening closed sectors to private capital. But private-sector firms are neither large nor rich enough to buy significant minority stakes in big SOEs and so would lack any real decision-making power. Domestic private entrepreneurs would feel more comfortable investing in small SOE subsidiaries or projects over which they have full control. Many private entrepreneurs still see the purchase of state assets as a high-risk, high-return business activity.
Though mixed ownership should produce more transparency, the strategic and managerial decisions will thus remain firmly in the hands of the state and the Communist Party. Promotion of senior management will continue to be driven largely by the un wieldy bureaucratic process under which appointments are made by Party’s Organization Department. The Party will maintain its cells in all companies and its discipline inspection teams will reinforce the current anti-corruption campaign.
The reform blueprint for the coming decade agreed by the Party Plenum last November said “the market will play a decisive role” but also that “the state sector remains dominant”. The first element was evident in the commitment to “actively develop mixed ownership” as a guiding principle for SOE reform, which has now been carried through in a pilot restructuring programme together with reform plans by big groups such as PetroChina, Sinopec and the China Everbright and by a dozen provincial governments of local SOEs.
That is an important breakthrough given the way in which SOE reform has been stalled this century after the modernisation undertaken by Premier Zhu Rongji in the 1990s. The massive fiscal stimulus launched at the end of 2008 used state firms as vehicles to translate the credit expansion into growth in the traditional manner of Chinese governments. But this intervention produces distortions, and the pervasive presence of government intervention compromised the allocative efficiency of capital and resources.
Without giving equal rights to private capital, SOE reform will not proceed quickly. Most SOEs have pursued capacity expansion at all costs based on a low-return high-leverage model, which had led to the industrial over-capacity that is one of China’s major weaknesses. They are widely believed to have gone into sectors in which the state has no natural comparative advantage, such as property, retail, home appliances and logistics, crowding out the private sector. This distorts the labour market and creates social disparities. We estimate the average income of SOE staff is 40-50 per cent higher than in the private-sector. Xi Jinping says executives should expect pay cuts and reduced perks.
SOE assets expanded by 512 per cent between. 2003 and 2013 to Rmb104tn ($16.9tn) – equivalent to more than 180 per cent of GDP. This expansion was funded mostly by debt: total equity for all SOEs stood at just Rmb37tn ($6tn) at the end of last year. Many still make profits, but average return on assets (ROA) fell in 2007 and has stagnated since, running at half the rate for private-sector firms and highlighting the need for change in companies that between them account for around three-quarters of capitalisation on the Shanghai A share index. (See chart).
Chart 1: Growth of ROA of industrial enterprises
Xi has become popular on the back of his wide-ranging anti-corruption campaign and with the arrest of highly-placed “big tigers”, but implementation of reform will require public support. People need to believe state-owned assets are being sold at a fair price – allegations of bargain basement disposals have been a powerful weapon deployed against reform in the past, with suspicions of profiteering by officials, well-connected wealthy people and SOE managers. The public does not seem to appreciate the added-value of improved management. Though the new team might turn losses into profit, the public questions asset pricing and has often accused the new owner of corruption. Such a blacklash could impede the whole process.
Take the cautionary tale of Gu Chujun and Kelong Electronics: Soon after Gu bought the loss-making company from the Shunde district government in Guangdong in 2002; a Hong Kong professor accused him of stealing state assets by pricing them too cheaply. Gu was investigated for alleged improper accounting and expropriating state assets. Detained in 2005, he was tried and in 2008 sentenced to 12 years in jail. Many experts see his story as a classic example of the ability of the government to violate the rights of private capitalists during the privatization of state-owned assets, especially if public opinion is aroused. The strongest catalyst for reform is likely to stem from a combination of heavier SOE losses and fiscal exhaustion of local governments which need funds from disposal of assets. This process will become apparent with sale of minority stakes, expanding to bigger holdings as fiscal pressure intensifies from 2016.
Success will require the various levels of government to refrain from economic intervention, and are ready to accept greater growth volatility with missed targets. That means shifting the overall governance structure to relax state control. Given Xi Jinping’s political stress on “Party Strengthening”, this involves an obvious top-level choice which runs through China’s reform agenda as a whole – and will confront politics and economics as the reform process moves ahead.
Bo Zhuang is Head of the Beijing Office of Trusted Sources, the emerging market research and analysis service. This is the first of a fortnightly series of guest posts by Trusted Sources on reform in emerging markets as outlined in Beyond the acronyms, EM reform is what really counts.
---
Guest post: China’s state enterprise reform could strengthen state
Sep 5, 2014 1:00amby guest writer
00
By Bo Zhuang of Trusted Sources
Overhauling state-owned enterprises (SOEs) is key to the Chinese growth story for the next 10 years. But, while the approach being taken by the Xi Jinping leadership acknowledges the need for change, it also stresses the parallel need to strengthen the Communist Party State. This could mean reform will take a rather different form to the assumptions of markets, which have risen on the back of expectations of market-friendly change.
Some elements of the reforms are starting to take shape. The State Assets Supervisory and Administrative Commission (SASAC), the national SOE umbrella organization, has proposed two new ownership forms. One involves state asset-holding companies to manage state-owned capital on the lines of Singapore’s Temasek. The State Development and Investment Corporation (SDIC) and the China National Cereals, Oils and Foodstuffs Corporation (COFCO) will be the first two platforms for this. Meanwhile, Sinopharm Group and the China National Building Materials Group will participate in a pilot programme aimed at mixed-ownership to give private capital bigger equity stakes in SOEs.
The XinXing Cathay International Group, China Energy Conservation Investment Corporation, Sinopharm and China National Building Materials will be in a scheme to let directors decide the assignment, evaluation and remuneration of senior executives.
The chosen companies are, for the most part, attractive investment targets. But the programme does not address two fundamental issues: breaking up monopolies and equality of political and legal status for private enterprises and SOEs. In addition, two major questions run through what will be a long process – the extent to which the state will relinquish control and the nature of “mixed ownership”.
The result could be what is known as a “mixed ownership monopoly model” with private capital boosting the resources of already-dominant state groups and thus strengthening their positions at the commanding heights of the economy. Genuine reform would involve opening closed sectors to private capital. But private-sector firms are neither large nor rich enough to buy significant minority stakes in big SOEs and so would lack any real decision-making power. Domestic private entrepreneurs would feel more comfortable investing in small SOE subsidiaries or projects over which they have full control. Many private entrepreneurs still see the purchase of state assets as a high-risk, high-return business activity.
Though mixed ownership should produce more transparency, the strategic and managerial decisions will thus remain firmly in the hands of the state and the Communist Party. Promotion of senior management will continue to be driven largely by the un wieldy bureaucratic process under which appointments are made by Party’s Organization Department. The Party will maintain its cells in all companies and its discipline inspection teams will reinforce the current anti-corruption campaign.
The reform blueprint for the coming decade agreed by the Party Plenum last November said “the market will play a decisive role” but also that “the state sector remains dominant”. The first element was evident in the commitment to “actively develop mixed ownership” as a guiding principle for SOE reform, which has now been carried through in a pilot restructuring programme together with reform plans by big groups such as PetroChina, Sinopec and the China Everbright and by a dozen provincial governments of local SOEs.
That is an important breakthrough given the way in which SOE reform has been stalled this century after the modernisation undertaken by Premier Zhu Rongji in the 1990s. The massive fiscal stimulus launched at the end of 2008 used state firms as vehicles to translate the credit expansion into growth in the traditional manner of Chinese governments. But this intervention produces distortions, and the pervasive presence of government intervention compromised the allocative efficiency of capital and resources.
Without giving equal rights to private capital, SOE reform will not proceed quickly. Most SOEs have pursued capacity expansion at all costs based on a low-return high-leverage model, which had led to the industrial over-capacity that is one of China’s major weaknesses. They are widely believed to have gone into sectors in which the state has no natural comparative advantage, such as property, retail, home appliances and logistics, crowding out the private sector. This distorts the labour market and creates social disparities. We estimate the average income of SOE staff is 40-50 per cent higher than in the private-sector. Xi Jinping says executives should expect pay cuts and reduced perks.
SOE assets expanded by 512 per cent between. 2003 and 2013 to Rmb104tn ($16.9tn) – equivalent to more than 180 per cent of GDP. This expansion was funded mostly by debt: total equity for all SOEs stood at just Rmb37tn ($6tn) at the end of last year. Many still make profits, but average return on assets (ROA) fell in 2007 and has stagnated since, running at half the rate for private-sector firms and highlighting the need for change in companies that between them account for around three-quarters of capitalisation on the Shanghai A share index. (See chart).
Chart 1: Growth of ROA of industrial enterprises
Xi has become popular on the back of his wide-ranging anti-corruption campaign and with the arrest of highly-placed “big tigers”, but implementation of reform will require public support. People need to believe state-owned assets are being sold at a fair price – allegations of bargain basement disposals have been a powerful weapon deployed against reform in the past, with suspicions of profiteering by officials, well-connected wealthy people and SOE managers. The public does not seem to appreciate the added-value of improved management. Though the new team might turn losses into profit, the public questions asset pricing and has often accused the new owner of corruption. Such a blacklash could impede the whole process.
Take the cautionary tale of Gu Chujun and Kelong Electronics: Soon after Gu bought the loss-making company from the Shunde district government in Guangdong in 2002; a Hong Kong professor accused him of stealing state assets by pricing them too cheaply. Gu was investigated for alleged improper accounting and expropriating state assets. Detained in 2005, he was tried and in 2008 sentenced to 12 years in jail. Many experts see his story as a classic example of the ability of the government to violate the rights of private capitalists during the privatization of state-owned assets, especially if public opinion is aroused. The strongest catalyst for reform is likely to stem from a combination of heavier SOE losses and fiscal exhaustion of local governments which need funds from disposal of assets. This process will become apparent with sale of minority stakes, expanding to bigger holdings as fiscal pressure intensifies from 2016.
Success will require the various levels of government to refrain from economic intervention, and are ready to accept greater growth volatility with missed targets. That means shifting the overall governance structure to relax state control. Given Xi Jinping’s political stress on “Party Strengthening”, this involves an obvious top-level choice which runs through China’s reform agenda as a whole – and will confront politics and economics as the reform process moves ahead.
Bo Zhuang is Head of the Beijing Office of Trusted Sources, the emerging market research and analysis service. This is the first of a fortnightly series of guest posts by Trusted Sources on reform in emerging markets as outlined in Beyond the acronyms, EM reform is what really counts.